Monday, January 28, 2019
Japanese Industrialization and Economic Growth Essay
japan achieved sustained step-up in per capita income amid the 1880s and 1970 by means of industrialization. Moving a colossal an income suppu dimensionn trajectory finished working out of manufacturing is exactly unique. Indeed Western Europe, Canada, Australia and the unite landed estates all attained racy directs of income per capita by shifting from agrarian-based turn proscribed to manufacturing and technologically sophisticated service vault of heaven activity. Still, in that respect are four distinctive features of lacquers exploitation with industrialization that merit discussionThe proto-industrial basejapans countrified productiveness was high enough to sustain substantial craft (proto-industrial) business in both rural and urban areas of the earth prior to industrialization.Investment-led ripeningDomestic enthronement in industry and root was the driving draw in behind increment in Nipponese verbotenput. Both private and universe sectors inves ted in stem, home(a) and local political sympathiess serving as coordinating agents for infrastructure build-up. * Investment in manufacturing efficiency was more often than not left to the private sector. * wage increase interior(prenominal) savings made increasing chapiter accumulation possible. * lacquerese growth was investment-led, not export-led.Total fixings productivity growth achieving much egressput per unit of measurement of input was fast. On the supply side, center factor productivity growth was extremely important. Scale economies the reduction in per unit costs due to change magnitude levels of output contributed to score factor productivity growth. Scale economies existed due to geographic concentration, to growth of the national economy, and to growth in the output of individual companies. In addition, companies moved level the learning curve, trim back unit costs as their cumulative output rose and choose for their product soared. The fon d capacity for import and adapting unknown engine room alter and this contributed to total factor productivity growth * At the household level, investment funds in study of children improved favorable potentiality.* At the firm level, creating internalized lowtaking markets that bound firms to workers and workers to firms, thereby giving workers a strong incentive to flexibly adapt to new engineering science, improved social capability. * At the presidential term level, industrial policy that reduced the cost to private firms of securing conflicting technology compound social capacity. Shifting out of low-productivity repose into high productivity manufacturing, mining, and twisting contributed to total factor productivity growth.DualismSharply segmented diligence and big(p) markets emerged in japan after the 1910s. The ceiling intense sector enjoying high ratios of bang-up to draw back paid relatively high wages, and the stab intensive sector paid relatively low wages. Dualism contributed to income inequality and therefore to domestic social unrest. later 1945 a series of domain policy straighten outs communicate inequality and erased much of the social bitterness around dualism that ravaged lacquer prior to pieceness War II. The remainder of this article will stretch on a number of the themes mentioned above. The app dismis sextette reviews quantitative evidence concerning these confidential informations. The finish of the article lists references that provide a wealth of detailed evidence musical accompaniment the points above, which this article can only begin to explore. The Legacy of Autarky and the Proto-Industrial economy Achievements of Tokugawa lacquer (1600-1868)Why japan?Given the relatively poor eternalise of countries outside the European cultural area few achieving the kind of catch-up growth japan managed betwixt 1880 and 1970 the question naturally arises why Japan? aft(prenominal) all, when the unify States forcibly opened Japan in the 1850s and Japan was force to cede extra-territorial mightilys to a number of Western nations as had China prior in the 1840s, many Westerners and Nipponese a same thought Japans prospects key outmed dim indeed.Tokugawa achievements urbanisation, road networks, rice cultivation, craft production In respond this question, Mosk (2001), Minami (1994) and Ohkawa and Rosovsky (1973) emphasize the achievements of Tokugawa Japan (1600-1868) during a long period of coatingd country autarky in the midst of the mid-seventeenth carbon and the 1850s a high level of urbanization easily genuine road networks the channeling of river water flow with embankments and the extensive elabo appreciateness of irrigation ditches that supported and encouraged the refinement of rice cultivation based upon alter seed varieties, fertilizers and planting methods especially in the Southwest with its relatively long growing season the development of proto-industria l (craft) production by merchant houses in the major(ip) cities like Osaka and Edo (now called capital of Japan) and its diffusion to rural areas after 1700 and the progress of learning and population control among both the military machine elite (the samurai) and the lucky peasantry in the eighteenth and primaeval nineteenth centuries. Tokugawa political economy daimyo and shogunThese developments were natural from the political economy of Japan. The system of confederation government introduced at the end of the fifteenth century placed certain index fingers in the hands of feudalistic warlords, daimyo, and certain proponents in the hands of the shogun, the around powerful of the warlords. Each daimyo and the shogun was depute a geographic region, a domain, being given taxation dictum over the peasants residing in the villages of the domain. Intercourse with foreign powers was monopolized by the shogun, thereby preventing daimyo from cementing alliances with acter( a) countries in an effort to overthrow the central government. The samurai military retainers of thedaimyo were agonistic to cast out rice husbandry and reside in the castle town home of their daimyo overlord.In exchange, samurai received rice stipends from the rice taxes collected from the villages of their domain. By removingsamurai from the countryside by demilitarizing rural areas conflicts over local water rights were largely made a thing of the past. As a result irrigation ditches were protracted without the valleys, and riverbanks were shored up with stone embankments, facilitating transport and preventing flooding. The sustained growth of proto-industrialization in urban Japan, and its widespread diffusion to villages after 1700 was too inseparable from the productivity growth in paddy rice production and the growing of industrial crops like tea, fruit, mulberry tree plant growing (that sustained the raising of silk cocoons) and cotton. Indeed, Smith (1988) has gi ven experience of place to these domestic sources of Japans future industrial success. zeal to emulate the WestAs a result of these domestic advances, Japan was well positioned to take up the Western challenge. It harnessed its infrastructure, its high level of literacy, and its proto-industrial distribution networks to the task of emulating Western organizational forms and Western techniques in force production, premiere and foremost enlisting in entire energy sources like char and the different fossil fuels to generate steamer power. Having intensively developed the organic economy depending upon natural energy flows like wind, water and fire, Nipponese were quite prepared to master inorganic production after the Black Ships of the Americans forced Japan to jettison its long-standing autarky.From Balanced to Dualistic reaping, 1887-1938 Infrastructure and Manufacturing Expand Fukoku KyoheiAfter the Tokugawa government collapsed in 1868, a new Meiji government connected to the fit policies of fukoku kyohei (wealthy country/strong military) took up the challenge of renegotiating its treaties with the Western powers. It created infrastructure that facilitated industrialization. It reinforced a modern navy and army that could keep the Western powers at bay and establish a protective buffer zone in North East Asia that eventually formed the basis for a burgeoning Nipponese empire in Asia and the peaceful. Central government reforms in education, finance and fare Jettisoning the confederation style government of the Tokugawa era, the new leaders of the new Meiji government fashioned a unitary state with powerful ministries consolidating authority in the capital, Tokyo.The freshly minted Ministry of Education promoted compulsory primary schooling for the masses and elite university education aimed at deepening engineering and scientific acquaintance. The Ministry of Finance created the stick of Japan in 1882, laying the foundations for a private bank ing system support up a lender of last resort. The government began building a steam railroad trunk line girding the four major islands, back up private companies to affairicipate in the project. In particular, the national government committed itself to constructing a Tokaido line connecting the Tokyo/Yokohama region to the Osaka/Kobe conurbation along the Pacific coastline of the main island of Honshu, and to creating deepwater harbors at Yokohama and Kobe that could accommodate deep-hulled steamships. Not surprisingly, the merchants in Osaka, the merchant capital of Tokugawa Japan, already well versed in proto-industrial production, turned to harnessing steam and coal, investment heavily in integrated spinning and weaving steam- pokingn textile mill about during the 1880s.Diffusion of surmount- make husbandryAt the same time, the abolition of the three atomic number 6 or so feudal fiefs that were the backbone of confederation style-Tokugawa rule and their integrating int o politically weak prefectures, under a strong national government that virtually monopolized taxation authority, gave a strong push to the diffusion of best put on unsophisticated technique. The nationwide diffusion of seed varieties developed in the Southwest fiefs of Tokugawa Japan spearheaded a substantial improvement in agricultural productivity especially in the Northeast. Simultaneously, expansion of agriculture utilise traditionalistic Japanese technology agriculture and manufacturing using imported Western technology resulted.Balanced growth egress at the close of the nineteenth century was balanced in the sense that traditional and modern technology using sectors grew at roughly equal rates, and get the picture especially young girls recruited out of farm households to moil in the steam using textile mill around flowed back and forth between rural and urban Japan at wages that were roughly equal in industrial and agricultural pursuits. geographical economies of crustal plate in the Tokaido crashConcentration of industrial production first in Osaka and ulteriorly without the Tokaido belt fostered powerful geographic racing shell economies (the ability to reduce per unit costs as output levels increase), cut back the costs of securing energy, raw materials and access to global markets for enterprises located in the spectacular harbor metropolises stretching from the massive Osaka/Kobe complex northward to the teeming Tokyo/Yokohama conurbation. Between 1904 and 1911, electrification mainly due to the proliferation of intercity electrical railroads created economies of scale in the nascent industrial belt facing outward onto the Pacific. The consolidation of two grand hydroelectric power grids during the mid-twenties one servicing Tokyo/Yokohama, the otherwise Osaka and Kobe further solidified the comparative advantage of the Tokaido industrial belt in factory production. Finally, the siding and paving during the 1920s of roads t hat could handle buses and trucks was also pioneered by the great metropolises of the Tokaido, which further bolstered their relative advantage in per capita infrastructure.organisational economies of scale zaibatsuIn addition to geographic scale economies, organizational scale economies also became increasingly important in the late nineteenth centuries. The geological formation of the zaibatsu (financial cliques), which gradually evolved into diversified industrial combines tied in concert by central holding companies, is a case in point. By the 1910s these had evolved into passing diversified combines, binding together enterprises in banking and insurance, trading companies, mining concerns, textiles, fight and steel plants, and machinery manufactures. By channeling profits from older industries into new lines of activity like electrical machinery manufacturing, the zaibatsu form of organization generated scale economies in finance, batch and manufacturing, drastically red ucing information-gathering and transactions costs. By attracting relatively scare managerial and entrepreneurial talent, the zaibatsu format economized on human resources.ElectrificationThe push into electrical machinery production during the 1920s had a revolutionary impact on manufacturing. Effective exploitation of steam power required the use of large central steam engines simultaneously driving a large number of machines power looms and mules in a spinning/weaving plant for instance throughout a factory. clarified enterprises did not mechanize in the steam era. But with electrification the unit drive system of mechanization spread. Each machine could be powered up independently of one another(prenominal). Mechanization spread rapidly to the smallest factory.Emergence of the Manichaean economyWith the drive into heavy industries chemicals, iron and steel, machinery the solicit for skilled labor that would flexibly respond to rapid changes in technique soared. Large fir ms in these industries began offering premium wages and guarantees of employment in good generation and bad as a way of motivating and holding onto important workers. A dualistic economy emerged during the 1910s. Small firms, light industry and agriculture offered relatively low wages. Large enterprises in the heavy industries offered much to a greater extent favorable remuneration, extending paternalistic benefits like company housing and company wellbeing programs to their internal labor markets. As a result a widening gulf opened up between the great metropolitan centers of the Tokaido and rural Japan. Income per head was far higher in the great industrial centers than in the hinterland.Clashing urban/rural and landlord/tenant interestsThe stinting strains of emergent dualism were amplified by the slowing down of technological progress in the agricultural sector, which had soundly reaped the benefits due to regional diffusion from the Southwest to the Northeast of best prac tice Tokugawa rice cultivation. Landlords around 45% of the cultivable rice paddy land in Japan was held in some form of tenancy at the beginning of the twentieth century who had played a crucial position in promoting the diffusion of traditional best practice techniques now broken interest in rural affairs and turned their attention to industrial activities. tenants also found their interests disregarded by the national authorities in Tokyo, who were increasingly focused on supplying cheap foodstuffs to the burgeoning industrial belt by promoting agricultural production within the empire that it was assembling through military victories. Japan secured Taiwan from China in 1895, and formally brought Korea under its imperial lodged rule in 1910 upon the heels of its successful war a take a leakst Russia in 1904-05. Tenant unions reacted to this callous disrespect of their needs through violence. Landlord/tenant disputes broke out in the early 1920s, and continued to plague Japan politically throughout the 1930s, calls for land reform and bureaucratic proposals for reform being rejected by a Diet (Japans legislature) politically dominated by landlords.Japans military expansionJapans thrust to imperial expansion was inflamed by the growing instability of the geopolitical and multinationalist trade regime of the later 1920s and early 1930s. The relative downslope of the United Kingdom as an economic power doomed a gold standard regime tied to the British pound. The United States was become a potential contender to the United Kingdom as the disciple of a gold standard regime but its long register of high tariffs and isolationism deterred it from taking over leadership in promoting global trade openness. Germany and the Soviet Union were increasingly becoming industrial and military giants on the Eurasian land mass committed to ideologies hostile to the liberal nation championed by the United Kingdom and the United States. It was against this internatio nal backdrop that Japan began aggressively staking out its claim to being the dominant military power in East Asia and the Pacific, thereby bringing it into conflict with the United States and the United Kingdom in the Asian and Pacific theaters after the adult male slipped into global warfare in 1939.Reform and Re mental synthesis in a raw International economical Order, Japan after World War II Postwar occupation economic and institutional restructuring Surrendering to the United States and its allies in 1945, Japans economy and infrastructure was revamped under the S.C.A.P (Supreme Commander of the assort Powers) Occupation lasting through 1951. As Nakamura (1995) points out, a classification of Occupation-sponsored reforms modify the institutional environment conditioning economic performance in Japan.The major zaibatsu were liquidated by the Holding Company Liquidation Commission set up under the Occupation (they were revamped as keiretsu corporate groups mainly tied toge ther through cross-shareholding of stock in the aftermath of the Occupation) land reform wiped out landlordism and gave a strong push to agricultural productivity through mechanization of rice cultivation and collective bargaining, largely illegal under the stop Preservation Act that was used to suppress union organizing during the interwar period, was given the sanction of constitutional legality. Finally, education was opened up, partly through making centre of attention school compulsory, partly through the creation of national universities in separately of Japans forty-six prefectures.Improvement in the social capability for economic growthIn short, from a domestic point of view, the social capability for importing and adapting foreign technology was improved with the reforms in education and the fillip to competition given by the dissolution of the zaibatsu. Resolving tenseness between rural and urban Japan through land reform and the establishment of a rice price support program that guaranteed farmers incomes equal to blue collar industrial workers also contributed to the social capacity to truckle foreign technology by suppressing the political divisions between metropolitan and hinterland Japan that plagued the nation during the interwar years.Japan and the postwar international orderThe revamped international economic order contributed to the social capability of importing and adapting foreign technology. The instability of the 1920s and 1930s was replaced with replaced with a relatively predictable bipolar world in which the United States and the Soviet Union opposed each other in both geopolitical and ideological arenas. The United States became an architect of four-sided architecture designed to encourage trade through its sponsorship of the United Nations, the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund and the General Agreement on Tariffs and lot (the predecessor to the World cover Organization). Under the logic of building military alliances to contain Eurasian Communism, the United States brought Japan under its nuclear umbrella with a bilateral security treaty. American companies were encouraged to license technology to Japanese companies in the new international environment. Japan redirected its trade outside from the areas that had been incorporated into the Japanese Empire before 1945, and towards the huge and expanding American market.Miracle reaping Soaring Domestic Investment and Export harvest-tide, 1953-1970 Its infrastructure revitalized through the Occupation period reforms, its capacity to import and export enhanced by the new international economic order, and its access to American technology bolstered through its security pact with the United States, Japan experienced the dramatic Miracle appendage between 1953 and the early 1970s whose sources have been cogently analyzed by Denison and Chung (1976). in particular striking in the Miracle Growth period was the remarkable increase in the rate of domestic fixed capital formation, the rise in the investment proportion being matched by a rising savings rate whose secular increase especially that of private household savings has been well documented and analyzed by Horioka (1991). While Japan continued to close the gap in income per capita between itself and the United States after the early 1970s, most scholars believe that large Japanese manufacturing enterprises had by and large become internationally competitive by the early 1970s. In this sense it can be said that Japan had completed its nine decade long crossing to international competitiveness through industrialization by the early 1970s.MITI on that point is little doubt that the social capacity to import and adapt foreign technology was vastly improved in the aftermath of the Pacific War. Creating social consensus with Land Reform and agricultural subsidies reduced political divisiveness, extending compulsory education and breaking up the zaibatsu had a positive impact. Fashioning the Ministry of International Trade and Industry (M.I.T.I.) that took responsibility for overseeing industrial policy is also viewed as facilitating Japans social capability. There is no doubt that M.I.T.I. drove down the cost of securing foreign technology. By intervening between Japanese firms and foreign companies, it acted as a single buyer of technology, playing off competing American and European enterprises in order to reduce the royalties Japanese concerns had to pay on technology licenses. By keeping domestic patent periods short, M.I.T.I. encouraged rapid diffusion of technology.And in some cases the experience of International Business Machines (I.B.M.), enjoying a virtual monopoly in global mainframe computer markets during the 1950s and early 1960s, is a classical case M.I.T.I. made it a condition of intro into the Japanese market (through the creation of a subsidiary Japan I.B.M. in the case of I.B.M.) that foreign companies share many of their te chnological secrets with potential Japanese competitors. How important industrial policy was for Miracle Growth remains controversial, however. The view of Johnson (1982), who hails industrial policy as a pillar of the Japanese increase State (government promoting economic growth through state policies) has been criticized and revised by subsequent scholars. The book by Uriu (1996) is a case in point. Internal labor markets, just-in-time inventory and quality control circles Furthering the internalization of labor markets the premium wages and long-term employment guarantees largely restricted to white collar workers were extended to blue collar workers with the legalization of unions and collective bargaining after 1945 also raised the social capability of adapting foreign technology.Internalizing labor created a extremely flexible labor force in post-1950 Japan. As a result, Japanese workers embraced many of the key ideas of Just-in-Time inventory control and Quality Control c ircles in assembly industries, learning how to do rapid machine setups as part and parcel of an effort to produce components just-in-time and without defect. Ironically, the concepts of just-in-time and quality control were originally developed in the United States, just-in-time methods being pioneered by supermarkets and quality control by efficiency experts like W. Edwards Deming. Yet it was in Japan that these concepts were relentlessly engage to revolutionize assembly line industries during the 1950s and 1960s.Ultimate causes of the Japanese economic miracleMiracle Growth was the completion of a protracted historical process involving enhancing human capital, massive accumulation of physical capital including infrastructure and private manufacturing capacity, the meaning and adaptation of foreign technology, and the creation of scale economies, which took decades and decades to true(a)ize. Dubbed a miracle, it is best seen as the reaping of a bountiful harvest whose seeds wer e painstakingly planted in the six decades between 1880 and 1938. In the course of the nine decades between the 1880s and 1970, Japan amassed and lost a sprawling empire, reorienting its trade and geopolitical stance through the twists and turns of history. While the ultimate sources of growth can be ferreted out through some form of statistical vizoring, the specific way these sources were marshaled in practice is inseparable from the history of Japan itself and of the global environment within which it has recognise its industrial destiny.Appendix Sources of Growth Accounting and Quantitative Aspects of Japans Modern Economic Development One of the attractions of studying Japans post-1880 economic development is the abundance of quantitative data documenting Japans growth. Estimates of Japanese income and output by sector, capital stock and labor force extend back to the 1880s, a period when Japanese income per capita was low. Consequently statistical probing of Japans long-run growth from relative poorness to abundance is possible.The remainder of this appendix is devoted to introducing the reader to the vast literature on quantitative compendium of Japans economic development from the 1880s until 1970, a nine decade period during which Japanese income per capita converged towards income per capita levels in Western Europe. As the reader will see, this discussion confirms the richness of factors discussed at the outset of this article. Our initial touchstone is the excellent sources of growth accounting analysis carried out by Denison and Chung (1976) on Japans growth between 1953 and 1971. Attributing growth in national income in growth of inputs, the factors of production capital and labor and growth in output per unit of the two inputs feature (total factor productivity) along the following lines G(Y) = a G(K) + 1-a G(L) + G (A)where G(Y) is the (annual) growth of national output, g(K) is the growth rate of capital services, G(L) is the growth rate of labor services, a is capitals share in national income (the share of income accruing to owners of capital), and G(A) is the growth of total factor productivity, is a standard approach used to close together(p) the sources of growth of income. Using a variant of this type of decomposition that takes into account improvements in the quality of capital and labor, estimates of scale economies and adjustments for structural change (shifting labor out of agriculture helps explain why total factor productivity grows), Denison and Chung (1976) generate a useful set of estimates for Japans Miracle Growth era.Operating with this sources of growth approach and proceeding under a variety of plausible assumptions, Denison and Chung (1976) estimate that of Japans average annual real national income growth of 8.77 % over 1953-71, input growth accounted for 3.95% (accounting for 45% of total growth) and growth in output per unit of input contributed 4.82% (accounting for 55% of total grow th). To be sure, the precise assumptions and techniques they use can be criticized. The precise numeric results they arrive at can be argued over. Still, their general point that Japans growth was the result of improvements in the quality of factor inputs wellness and education for workers, for instance and improvements in the way these inputs are utilized in production due to technological and organizational change, reallocation of resources from agriculture to non-agriculture, and scale economies, is defensible.Notes a Maddison (2000) provides estimates of real income that take into account the purchasing power of national currencies. b Ohkawa (1979) gives estimates for the N sector that is defined as manufacturing and mining (Ma) improver construction plus facilitating industry (transport, communications and utilities). It should be noted that the concept of an N sector is not standard in the field of economics. c The estimates of trade are obtained by adding merchandise imp orts to merchandise exports. Trade openness is estimated by taking the ratio of total (merchandise) trade to national output, the latter defined as earn Domestic Product (G.D.P.).The trade figures include trade with Japans empire (Korea, Taiwan, Manchuria, etc.) the income figures for Japan exclude income generated in the empire. d The Human Development indication is a composite variable formed by adding together indices for educational attainment, for health (using life expectancy that is inversely related to the level of the baby mortality rate, the IMR), and for real per capita income. For a detailed discussion of this index see United Nations Development Programme (2000). e Electrical generation is measured in million kilowatts generated and supplied. For 1970, the figures on NHK subscribers are for television subscribers. The symbol n.a. = not available. Sources The figures in this table are taken from various pages and tables in Japan statistical Association (1987), Maddison (2000), Minami (1994), and Ohkawa (1979).Flowing from this table are a number of points that bear lessons of the Denison and Chung (1976) decomposition. One cluster of points bears upon the timing of Japans income per capita growth and the consanguinity of manufacturing expansion to income growth. Another highlights improvements in the quality of the labor input. Yet another points to the overriding importance of domestic investment in manufacturing and the lesser importation of trade demand. A fourth group suggests that infrastructure has been important to economic growth and industrial expansion in Japan, as exemplified by the figures on electricity generating capacity and the mass diffusion of communications in the form of radio and television broadcasting. Several parts of Table 1 point to industrialization, defined as an increase in the proportion of output (and labor force) attributable to manufacturing and mining, as the driving force in explaining Japans income per capita growth. Notable in venires A and B of the table is that the gap between Japanese and American income per capita closed most decisively during the 1910s, the 1930s, and the 1960s, precisely the periods when manufacturing expansion was the most vigorous.Equally noteworthy of the spurts of the 1910s, 1930s and the 1960s is the overriding importance of gross domestic fixed capital formation, that is investment, for growth in demand. By contrast, trade seems much less important to growth in demand during these critical decades, a point emphasized by both Minami (1994) and by Ohkawa and Rosovsky (1973). The notion that Japanese growth was export led during the nine decades between 1880 and 1970 when Japan caught up technologically with the leading Western nations is not defensible. Rather, domestic capital investment seems to be the driving force behind accumulate demand expansion. The periods of especially intense capital formation were also the periods when manufacturing production s oared. Capital formation in manufacturing, or in infrastructure reenforcement manufacturing expansion, is the main agent pushing long-run income per capita growth.Why? As Ohkawa and Rosovsky (1973) argue, spurts in manufacturing capital formation were associated with the import and adaptation of foreign technology, especially from the United States These investment spurts were also associated with shifts of labor force out of agriculture and into manufacturing, construction and facilitating sectors where labor productivity was far higher than it was in labor-intensive farming centered around labor-intensive rice cultivation. The logic of productivity gain due to more efficient allocation of labor resources is apparent from the right hand column of Panel A in Table 1. Finally, Panel C of Table 1 suggests that infrastructure investment that facilitated health and educational attainment (combined public and private expenditure on sanitation, schools and research laboratories), and pub lic/private investment in physical infrastructure including dams and hydroelectric power grids helped fuel the expansion of manufacturing by improving human capital and by reducing the costs of transportation, communications and energy supply faced by private factories.Mosk (2001) argues that investments in human-capital-enhancing (medicine, public health and education), financial (banking) and physical infrastructure (harbors, roads, power grids, railroads and communications) laid the groundwork for industrial expansions. Indeed, the social capability for importing and adapting foreign technology emphasized by Ohkawa and Rosovsky (1973) can be largely explained by an infrastructure-driven growth hypothesis like that given by Mosk (2001). In sum, Denison and Chung (1976) argue that a combination of input factor improvement and growth in output per combined factor inputs account for Japans most rapid spurt of economic growth. Table 1 suggests that labor quality improved because healt h was enhanced and educational attainment increased that investment in manufacturing was important not only because it increased capital stock itself but also because it reduced dependence on agriculture and went hand in glove with improvements in knowledge and that the social capacity to absorb and adapt Western technology that fueled improvements in knowledge was associated with infrastructure investment.ReferencesDenison, Edward and William Chung. Economic Growth and Its Sources. In Asias Next teras How the Japanese Economy Works, redact by Hugh Patrick and Henry Rosovsky, 63-151. Washington, DC Brookings Institution, 1976. Horioka, Charles Y. futurity Trends in Japans Savings Rate and the Implications Thereof for Japans External Imbalance.Japan and the World Economy 3 (1991) 307-330. Japan Statistical Association. historic Statistics of Japan Five Volumes. Tokyo Japan Statistical Association, 1987. Johnson, Chalmers. MITI and the Japanese Miracle The Growth of Industrial Poli cy, 1925-1975. Stanford Stanford University Press, 1982. Maddison, Angus. Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992. Paris Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2000. Minami, Ryoshin. Economic Development of Japan A Quantitative Study. Second edition. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire Macmillan Press, 1994. Mitchell, Brian. International Historical Statistics Africa and Asia. refreshed York New York University Press, 1982. Mosk, Carl. Japanese Industrial History Technology, Urbanization, and Economic Growth. Armonk, New York M.E. Sharpe, 2001. Nakamura, Takafusa. The Postwar Japanese Economy Its Development and Structure, 1937-1994. Tokyo University of Tokyo Press, 1995. Ohkawa, Kazushi. toil Structure. In Patterns of Japanese Economic Development A Quantitative Appraisal, edited by Kazushi Ohkawa and Miyohei Shinohara with Larry Meissner, 34-58. New Haven Yale UniversityPress, 1979. Ohkawa, Kazushi and Henry Rosovsky. Japanese Economic Growth Trend Acceleration i n the Twentieth Century. Stanford, CA Stanford University Press, 1973. Smith, Thomas. Native Sources of Japanese Industrialization, 1750-1920. Berkeley University of California Press, 1988. Uriu, Robert. Troubled Industries Confronting Economic Challenge in Japan. Ithaca Cornell University Press, 1996. United Nations Development Programme. Human Development Report, 2000. New York Oxford University Press, 2000. Citation Mosk, Carl. Japan, Industrialization and Economic Growth. EH.Net Encyclopedia, edited by Robert Whaples. January 18, 2004. URL http//eh.net/encyclopedia/article/mosk.japan.final
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment